Market failure occurs where the free-market equilibrium does not lead to a socially optimal allocation of resources such that too much or little of the good is produced.
In some cases, intervention of the government would be needed to address the causes of market failure and correct it whilst promoting stability and welfare. However, this belief lies on the school of economic thought one follows. For example, Laissez-Faire economists would believe that a free market, driven by the market forces of supply and demand, would eventually be able to correct the market failure naturally.
But even if intervention is needed, each government intervention method varies according to the specific type of market failure present.
It is important to note that other factors can be considered as market failures such as inequality gaps, emergence of monopolies and unemployment, all of which can be caused by allowing markets to run freely without intervention.
Private, external and social costs and benefits
social cost = private cost + external cost
social benefit = private benefit + external benefit
Merit and demerit goods
Externalities diagrams
Negatives externalities diagram: overproduction or overconsumption
Negative externalities occur when social costs exceed private costs, as a result of production or consumption. The quantity that the good or service is currently being consumed or produced at, is QME, which shows an overconsumption or production of the good or service, as it is currently higher than QSOP (the socially optimum amount of consumption or production, where the private costs=social costs). This leads to a total welfare loss, shown by the red triangle, where that is how much society is losing out as a result of the over consumption or production of the product.
Positive externalities diagram: underproduction or underconsumption
In a free market economy, merit goods are usually under consumed, shown by the diagram below:
The goods shown in this diagram are currently being under consumed or under produced at QME, whereas it should be at the socially optimum level, QSOP. This means that there is currently societal benefits on third parties that are currently being missed out on due to underconsumption or production, showed by the green triangle. This represents the total welfare that a society could gain if this good was consumed or produced at the socially optimum level.
To encourage production and consumption at the socially optimum level, the government could:
Public goods: A good provided without profit, where the ownership is not restricted to those that purchase it.
Private goods: A good provided with profit, where the ownership is restricted to those who purchase it.
Rivalrous:
Excludability:
Public goods are non-rivalrous and non-excludable in that they do not reduce the amount available for consumption for others when consumed, and the ownership is not restricted by purchasing it, as the goods are publically provided at no cost.
Examples of public goods:
Quasi-public goods
These are public goods which have elements of non-excludability and non-rivalrous, within them but are not completely non-excludable and non-rivalrous. An example is roads, where once provided, the afterwards consumption of them is not limited to others after initial consumption. However, when using the road, the benefit provided to the consumer may be reduced if congestion occurs, making roads partially rivalrous at times.
Schools of economics on the provision of public goods
The free rider problem
A free rider is someone who receives a benefit, without paying for the good. The free rider problem is a type of market failure that occurs when consumers do not pay their share from the consumption of public goods. This disincentivises producers to produce them due to no profits being made, resulting in no public goods being provided. This means that the government has to intervene and provide these public good, thus correcting the market failure.
Information gaps occur in an economic transaction when one party has more knowledge about the product at exchange, than the other party involved, which is also called a problem of asymmetric information. This problem can be extended by persuasive and misleading advertisement. Examples of asymmetric information could be: if a mechanic overcharged a consumer for repairs to their car or a taxi in a foreign country charging large sums of money for a short journey.
Information gaps can be filled by the internet, or by the government providing information to consumers. For example, users on social media such as instagram or tiktok may advise individuals to not visit certain places due to prior experiences where they have not recieved a good value for their money.
Government intervention refers to the actions taken by governments around the world, aiming to influence and/or regulate activities within an economy. This can include a variety of methods, such as regulations, taxes and subsidies. These approaches hold the intent of correcting market failures or achieving specific objectives.
An indirect tax is a tax on spending. i.e. it's a tax that is applied to a producer that forces them to put up the price of the good or service in some way. Normally, the government places indirect taxes on goods and/or services that create negative externalities, also known as excise duties. This implementation is strategically employed to disincentivize the production or consumption of demerit goods or services. This would reduce market failure as the price would be pushed up, meaning that output would fall to a more socially optimum level. Both types of indirect taxes are applicable to correct market failure, Ad Valorem or Specific.
As shown on the diagram: A newly induced tax will cause a fall in supply and increase costs to an individual so S=MPC shifts to S1=MPC1. The free market produces at PQ, where MPC=MPB but the socially optimum position of production is at P1Q1, where MSB=MSC. The equilibrium position is now S1=MPC1=MSC=MSB. Therefore, the tax internalises the externality and social welfare is now maximised.
Advantages of using indirect taxation
Disadvantages of using indirect taxation
A subsidy is a set amount of money given directly to a firm by the government to encourage consumption and production. In other words, the government pays part of the cost of the goods. A subsidy would be given to a staple good or a good that benefits society, for example, electric cars or the NHS. Subsidies are normally used by the government to increase consumption of merit goods and/or services, reducing market failure. This is because if a subsidy is applied to a merit good, supply will shift outwards resulting in the new equilibrium being closer to the socially optimum equilibrium. This results in the price of the merit goods falling, and the quantity increases towards the social optimum, extending demand and thus consumption for merit goods.
Advantages of using subsidies
Disadvantages of using subsidies
For a maximum price to take effect, it is implemented under the equilibrium price, but for a minimum price to be effective, it needs to be imposed above the equilibrium price. In practice, maximum and minimum prices have been implemented globally. For example, rent control in Manhattan, New York has had a maximum price imposed and Scotland has had a minimum price enforced on alcohol.
Maximum prices
A maximum price is usually established for a product exhibiting positive externalities, and is used to increase its affordability. Additionally, it may serve as a safeguard against monopolies exploiting consumers. This ceiling price often results in a situation where Quantity Demanded (QD) surpasses Quantity Supplied (QS), leading to excess demand.
Minimum prices
A minimum price is usually established for a product exhibiting negative externalities, and is used to decrease its affordability. This price floor often results in a situation where Quantity Supplied (QS) surpasses Quantity Demanded (QD), leading to excess supply.
Advantages of maximum and minimum prices
Social Welfare Increase: Both maximum and minimum prices can increase social welfare as they can be implemented where the Marginal Social Benefit (MSB) is equal to the Marginal Social Cost (MSC).
Maximum prices
Minimum prices
Disadvantages of maximum and minimum prices
Measurement issues: It may be hard to set the price floor or price ceiling because it may be hard to measure the effect of the externality that the government are trying to reduce, due to information gaps.
Maximum prices
Minimum prices
A tradeable pollution permit grants firms the authorization to emit a predetermined quantity of pollution, allocated by the government. Firms are obligated to purchase these permits, and to minimize expenses, companies decrease pollution output to avoid purchasing additional permits. Furthermore, these permits are exchangeable among firms for monetary compensation, which creates further pollution reduction efforts, as firms can profit by selling surplus permits. Due to the inelastic demand for these permits, firms can impose excessive prices on them. It is important to note that the supply of pollution permits is perfectly inelastic as there is a fixed quantity of permits available, distributed by the government.
Advantages of tradeable pollution permits
Disadvantages of tradeable pollution permits
Public goods, being both non-rivalrous and non-excludable, give rise to the free rider problem, and consequently, they are typically not supplied by the private sector or free market mechanisms. Instead, the government funds the provision of these merit goods through tax revenue.
Advantages of public goods provision
Disadvantages of public goods provision
When the market failure of asymmetric information occurs, the government may intervene and provide information to put both parties in an economic transaction in more equal positions, in terms of knowledge about the product. They can also do this by forcing companies to provide information about their product.
Advantages of the provision of information
Disadvantages of the provision of information
Governments may implement laws and caps that ensure that social welfare is maximised. The government has also introduced regulatory bodies in the UK, such as OFWAT (water) or OFCOM (communications).
Advantages of regulation
Disadvantages of regulation
The CMA is a non-ministerial government run department in the UK. They work to promote competition in the market and investigate mergers and acquisitions that may exploit consumers or be seen as too anti-competitive, with the power to stop them if they are seen as harmful. They are also able to impose criminal cases and penalties to anti-competitive firms who have been involved in collusive behaviours or cartels.
In the UK, mergers undergo examination, tailored to the specific scenario of each investigation, with a primary focus on whether there will be a Substantial Lessening of Competition (SLC), as a result of the merger. The CMA will carefully evaluate the anticipated merger including the effects of it upon economic agents and its competitors, juxtaposed with the scenario that the merger has never occurred, allowing them to see the full effect of the merger. The approval of the merger relies on whether the benefits of this transaction outweigh the costs.
A merger triggers investigation if they result in a market share exceeding 25%, or if they meet the turnover threshold of a combined turnover of £70 million plus, with the main goal being the prevention of consumer exploitation through higher prices or poorer quality. Overall, the CMA can stop firms from gaining monopolistic power, but very few mergers each year are actually investigated each year.
Profit regulation
Profit regulation is a regulatory mechanism used in highly concentrated markets such as monopolies. Under profit regulation, regulators set specific prices so that these monopolistic firms can charge for their goods and services, with the aim of ensuring that they earn a fair rate of return on their investments, whilst also considering the protection of consumers from excessively high prices.
For example, in the US, "rate of return" regulation is popular, where prices are set in a market that take into account the coverage of production costs with a rate of return on capital investment and the consumer. This encourages investment as firms are allowed to charge higher prices depending on their capital investment, but also may lead firms to shed labour thus creating unemployment.
Price regulation
Regulators are able to control prices making monopolistic firms below the profit maximising threshold, using the RPI-X formula, as shown below:
This formula for the regulatory price change is most commonly used in the airline industry.
Regulators are also able to use another system of the RPI-X+K formula, which has been argued to be more effective than the RPI-X formula, as shown below:
This formula for the regulatory price change is most commonly used in the water industry.
The second formula gives an incentive for firms to be as productively efficient as possible, as if costs fall below X, it results in increased profit. However, it is difficult for regulators to measure X due to asymmetric information. This means that there could be sudden price cuts in products, such as the 10% cut in water in 2000.
Performance targets
Performance targets refers to the specific objectives that regulators are looking for firms to achieve, by using certain aspects of goods and services, or production processes of other firms. For example, regulators have the option to implement yardstick competition, where regulators compare the performance of different entities within an industry to incentivise improvement. This has included setting up punctuality benchmarks for train operating companies, based on the top-performing European counterparts. Another approach relating to performance targets has been used in the water industry, which involves segmenting a service into regional sectors, thus encouraging comparison between different regions. These measures incentivise firms to enhance their service standards, which ultimately benefits consumers, in monopolistic markets. However, it is likely that firms may resist target implementation, meeting these targets without genuine improvement.
Competitive tendering
Public goods which are provided by the government, may not always be specifically produced by the government itself. For example, lots of the healthcare equipment used by the NHS is not directly produced by the NHS, but is purchased by the private sector. An example can also be used in services through Private Finance Initiatives (PFIs) which is when the government contracts private firms to run state provided operations. This can encourage competition into the market if the government looks to request competitive tenders by using a checklist to offer a private firm a contract, with the firm offering the lowest price being offered the contract. This is also beneficial to the government as it can reduce costs, thus saving money for expenditure in other state-run industries. However, this process is usually quite time consuming and can create an opportunity cost for time being used elsewhere.
Deregulation
Deregulation is the process by which rules are removed, or loosened from a market. By using deregulation, it can remove regulatory barriers to entry. In turn, this may increase competition, as it is easier for firms to enter the market.
Deregulation is used when there is excessive regulations in a market, also known as "red tape" or bureaucracy". An example of deregulation being used to foster competition, was the 1978 Airline Deregulation Act in the United States, which removed the Federal Government's control over things such as routes and regulatory barriers to entry. This deregulation allowed for new firms to enter the market, thus competition increased.
Privatisation
Privatisation is the process by which state owned assets are sold, and purchased by the private sector. A good example of this was the British Telecommunications Act which was passed in 1984, which allowed for the majority of British Telecom shares to be sold to the private sector. BT shares were listed on the London Stock Exchange, where 50.2% of it shares were bought by the private sector.
Economists who believe in a free market approach to the economy, believe that when firms are owned by the private sector, resources are allocated more efficiently because private sector firms are driven by the incentive of profit. This increase of allocative efficiency is likely to be paired with an increased quality of the products sold. Additionally, in the case of BT, once it was privatised, the once monopolistic telecom market, became a more competitive market, as privatisation was paired with deregulation.
Additionally, the sale of these assets to the private sector raises revenue for the government. However, this is only a one-off payment, so it may only be significant in the short-term.
Reducing the power of monopsonies
For many suppliers who operate in the primary sector, it is likely that they are exploited by the monopsony power of entities such as fast-food chains, supermarkets and restaurants. For example, many farmers have lost out to supermarkets in price wars, due to the fact that supermarkets keep on negotiating lower prices from alternative farmers, to lower their own prices and maximise profit and competition. However, this is disadvantageous to the farmers, because in some circumstances, they are unable to even make a normal profit, leading them to closure and leaving the market. The government is able to regulate this, so that suppliers are able to receive a fair exchange for their goods and services. For example, the government can use subsidies to support their production. Additionally, the Competition and Markets Authority (CMA) may investigate entities such as supermarkets, to ensure they are not abusing their monopsony power.
Nationalisation
Nationalisation is the process by which private sector assets are sold to the public sector, and control is no longer within the private sector e.g. the UK railways in 1948, coal mining in 1947, and the steel industry in 1947. Nationalisation creates natural monopolies, which can be advantageous for certain aspects of resource allocation, such as water provision. Conversely, nationalised industries aim to achieve alternate objectives compared to the privatised industries, in that increasing social welfare in a nationalised industry is more important than profit maximisation, which is the most desired objective in privatised industries.
It is likely for privatised firms to be operating at PQ, with nationalised firms at P1Q1.
Lowering prices
Increasing prices
Tax: Taxes such as corporation tax can lead to higher costs of production, which in turn fall negatively onto consumers in the form of higher prices.
Monopoly regulation: Government attempts to regulate monopolies, in some circumstances, can lead to regulatory capture, which ultimately leads to higher prices falling on consumers.
Profit
If the government uses intervention in the form of price caps, it may limit the amount of profit produced by firms. This can also negatively affect the economy if investment is reduced, as investment is a component of Aggregate Demand (AD).
Quality
Due to the nature of government intervention allowing the government to set performance targets, it may lead to increased quality of products by producers. Additionally, it is likely that firms in the private sector are already producing high quality products, in order to gain an edge in market share, due to non-price competition.
Choice
If the government use intervention, such as deregulation, to reduce barriers to entry, and allow more firms to enter the market, it is likely that consumers will have a wider range of products to choose from. However, if the government use price ceilings, and price floors, it is likely that firms may not be able to survive in the market, thus giving consumers less choice when shopping for their desired products.
Regulatory capture
Regulatory capture occurs when regulators start acting in consideration of the interests that firms they are regulating hold. This is a limitation to government intervention, because regulatory bodies may be regulating with the intent to help the firms they are supposed to be regulating, and not taking other economic agents, such as the consumers into account.
Asymmetric information
Asymmetric information may make it difficult for the government to know where to set regulation. Therefore, it is possible for them to set regulation that is disadvantageous to every economic agent e.g. setting a minimum price to high, or a maximum price too low etc.
Government failure occurs when government intervention leads to a net welfare loss and an inefficient allocation of resources in an economy. This net welfare loss occurs when the social cost arising from the initial intervention are greater than the social benefit arising from it. There are four potential causes of government failure: A Distortion in Price Signals, Information Gaps, Unintended Consequences and Administration Costs.
A distortion in price signals
Usually, the price signals in an economy are set by the free market mechanism, or the invisible hand. However, some types of government intervention may distort this mechanism, such as subsidies and taxes. For example, many farmers in the EU are heavily subsidised, as they are unable to produce goods at a competitive price, meaning that the government are the force that keeps them in business, thus distorting the price mechanism.
Information gaps
The decisions that governments make are usually based on previous data, that allows them to make a prediction about the future, thus allowing them to direct spending in the appropriate sectors. However, due to infinite external factors, it is usually impossible for the government to correctly predict any forecasts for the future. This means that the government may invest in sectors where the social costs outweigh the private costs thus leading to negative externalities, or general market failure, as a result of information gaps in the government.
Unintended consequences
Some methods of intervention used by the government to achieve objectives in a certain sector may distort success in other sectors, or other economic agents. For example, setting a minimum wage may be beneficial to certain workers, however, it may create unintended harms on producers, who simply can not afford to pay their labour at this cost, driving them out of business.
Excessive administration costs
In many public sector industries, the money used for expenditure is mostly used on administration costs. This means that the social costs could be higher than the social benefits, if money is not allocated as it would be expected to be in the correct places. For example, lots of money spent in the NHS is spent on organisation and admin costs, rather than the health care itself, leading to potential government failure.